3 ALL HAPPY COMPANIES ARE DIFFERENT

THE BUSINESS VERSION of our contrarian question  is: what valuable company is nobody building? This question is harder than it looks,  because your company could create   a lot of value without becoming very valuable itself. Creating value is not enough—you also need  to capture some of the value you  create. This means that even very big businesses can be bad businesses. For example, U.S. airline companies serve millions of passengers and create hundreds of billions  of dollars of value each year.  But in 2012, when the average airfare each way  was $178, the airlines made only 37 cents per passenger trip. Compare them to Google, which  creates less value but captures far more. Google brought in $50 billion in 2012 (versus  $160 billion for the airlines), but it kept 21% of those revenues as profits—more than 100 times the   airline industry’s profit margin  that year. Google makes so much money that it’s now worth three times  more than every U.S. airline combined.  The airlines compete with each other, but Google  stands alone. Economists use two simplified models to explain the difference:  perfect competition and monopoly. “Perfect competition” is considered both the  ideal and the default state in Economics 101. So called perfectly competitive markets achieve  equilibrium when producer supply meets consumer demand. Every firm in a competitive market is  undifferentiated and sells the same homogeneous products. Since no firm has any market power,  they must all sell at whatever price the market determines. If there is money to be  made, new firms will enter the market,   increase supply, drive prices down, and thereby eliminate the profits that attracted them  in the first place. If too many firms  enter the market, they’ll suffer  losses, some will fold, and prices will rise back to sustainable levels. Under perfect competition, in the   long run no company makes an economic profit. The opposite of perfect competition is monopoly. Whereas a competitive firm must sell at the market price, a monopoly owns its market,   so it can set its own prices.  Since it has no competition, it produces at the quantity and price  combination that maximizes its profits.  To an economist, every monopoly looks the same,  whether it deviously eliminates rivals, secures a license from the state, or innovates  its way to the top. In this book,   we’re not interested in illegal bullies or government favorites: by “monopoly,” we mean the kind  of company that’s so good at what  it does that no other firm can  offer a close substitute. Google is a good example of a company that went from 0 to 1: it hasn’t competed   in search since the early 2000s,  when it definitively distanced itself from Microsoft and Yahoo! Americans mythologize competition and credit   it with saving us from socialist bread lines. Actually, capitalism and competition are opposites. Capitalism is  premised on the accumulation of  capital, but under perfect competition all profits  get competed away. The lesson for entrepreneurs is clear: if you want to create and capture lasting  value, don’t build an undifferentiated commodity business.

LIES PEOPLE TELL

How much of the world is actually monopolistic?  How much is truly competitive? It’s hard to say, because our common conversation  about these matters is so   confused. To the outside observer, all businesses can seem reasonably alike, so it’s easy to perceive only small differences between them. But the reality is much more binary than that. There’s an enormous difference between perfect competition and monopoly, and most businesses are much closer to one extreme than we commonly realize.  The confusion comes from a universal bias for  describing market conditions in self-serving ways: both monopolists and competitors  are incentivized to bend the truth.

Monopoly Lies

Monopolists lie to protect themselves. They know that bragging about their great monopoly invites being audited, scrutinized, and attacked. Since they very much want their  monopoly profits to continue  unmolested, they tend to do whatever they can to  conceal their monopoly—usually by exaggerating the power of their (nonexistent) competition. Think about how Google talks about its business. It certainly doesn’t claim to be a monopoly. But is it one? Well, it depends: a monopoly in what? Let’s say that Google  is primarily a search engine.  As of May 2014, it owns about 68% of the search  market. (Its closest competitors, Microsoft and Yahoo!, have about 19% and 10%, respectively.) If  that doesn’t seem dominant enough, consider the fact that the word “google” is now an official  entry in the Oxford English Dictionary—as a verb. Don’t hold your breath waiting  for that to happen to Bing.  But suppose we say that Google is primarily an  advertising company. That changes things. The U.S. search engine advertising market is $17  billion annually. Online advertising is $37 billion annually. The entire U.S. advertising   market is $150 billion. And global  advertising is a $495 billion market. So even if Google completely  monopolized U.S. search   engine advertising, it would own just 3.4% of the global advertising market. From this angle, Google looks like a small player in a competitive world.  What if we frame Google as a multifaceted  technology company instead? This seems reasonable enough; in addition to its search engine, Google  makes dozens of other software products, not to mention robotic cars, Android phones, and wearable  computers. But 95% of Google’s revenue comes from search advertising; its other products  generated just $2.35 billion in 2012, and its consumer tech products a mere fraction   of that. Since consumer tech is a $964  billion market globally, Google owns less than 0.24% of it—a far cry from relevance,  let alone monopoly. Framing itself as just another tech company allows Google to escape all sorts of unwanted attention.

Competitive Lies

Non-monopolists tell the opposite lie: “we’re in a league  of our own.” Entrepreneurs are always  biased to understate the scale of  competition, but that is the biggest mistake a startup can make. The fatal temptation is to describe   your market extremely narrowly so  that you dominate it by definition. Suppose you want to start a restaurant that serves  British food in Palo Alto. “No one else is doing it,” you might reason. “We’ll own  the entire market.” But that’s   only true if the relevant market is the market for British food specifically. What if the actual market is the  Palo Alto restaurant market in  general? And what if all the restaurants in nearby  towns are part of the relevant market as well? These are hard questions, but  the bigger problem is that you   have an incentive not to ask them at all. When you hear that most new restaurants fail within one or two years,  your instinct will be to come  up with a story about how yours is  different. You’ll spend time trying to convince people that you are exceptional instead of seriously   considering whether that’s true.  It would be better to pause and consider whether there are people in Palo Alto who  would rather eat British food above all else. It’s very possible they don’t exist. In 2001, my co-workers at PayPal and I would often get lunch on Castro Street in Mountain View. We had our pick of restaurants,   starting with obvious categories like  Indian, sushi, and burgers. There were more options once we settled on a type: North  Indian or South Indian, cheaper or fancier, and so on. In contrast to the competitive  local restaurant market,   PayPal was at that time the only email- based payments company in the world. We employed fewer people than the restaurants on Castro Street did, but our business was much   more valuable than all of those  restaurants combined. Starting a new South Indian restaurant is a really hard way  to make money. If you lose sight of competitive reality and focus on trivial  differentiating factors—maybe you   think your naan is superior because of your great-grandmother’s recipe—your business is unlikely to survive. Creative industries work this way,   too. No screenwriter wants to  admit that her new movie script simply rehashes what has already been done before.  Rather, the pitch is: “This film will combine various exciting elements in entirely new ways.”  It could even be true. Suppose her idea is to have Jay-Z star in a cross between Hackers and Jaws:  rap star joins elite group of hackers to catch the shark that killed his friend. That has  definitely never been done before. But,   like the lack of British restaurants in Palo Alto, maybe that’s a good thing. Non-monopolists exaggerate   their distinction by defining their  market as the intersection of various smaller markets: British food ∩ restaurant ∩ Palo Alto  Rap star ∩ hackers ∩ sharks Monopolists, by contrast, disguise their monopoly by framing their market as the union of several large markets:  search engine ∪ mobile phones ∪  wearable computers ∪ self-driving cars What does a monopolist’s union story look like  in practice? Consider a statement from Google chairman Eric Schmidt’s testimony  at a 2011 congressional hearing:  We face an extremely competitive landscape in  which consumers have a multitude of options to access information. Or, translated from PR-speak to plain English:  Google is a small fish in a big pond. We could  be swallowed whole at any time. We are not the monopoly that the government is looking for.

RUTHLESS PEOPLE 

The problem with a competitive  business goes beyond lack of profits. Imagine you’re running one of those restaurants in Mountain View. You’re not   that different from dozens of your competitors, so you’ve got to fight hard to survive. If you offer affordable food with low margins, you can probably pay employees only minimum wage. And you’ll need to squeeze out every efficiency: that’s why small restaurants put Grandma to work   at the register and make the  kids wash dishes in the back. Restaurants aren’t much better even at the very  highest rungs, where reviews and ratings like  Michelin’s star system enforce  a culture of intense competition that can drive chefs crazy. (French chef and winner of three Michelin   stars Bernard Loiseau was quoted as  saying, “If I lose a star, I will commit suicide.” Michelin maintained his rating,  but Loiseau killed himself anyway in 2003 when a competing French dining guide  downgraded his restaurant.) The   competitive ecosystem pushes people toward ruthlessness or death. A monopoly like Google is different. Since it  doesn’t have to worry about competing with anyone, it has wider latitude to care about its workers,  its products, and its impact on the wider world. Google’s motto—“Don’t be evil”—is  in part a branding ploy, but it’s   also characteristic of a kind of business that’s successful enough to take ethics seriously without  jeopardizing its own existence. In  business, money is either an important thing or  it is everything. Monopolists can afford to think about things other than making  money; non-monopolists can’t.   In perfect competition, a business is so focused on today’s margins that it can’t possibly plan for a long-term  future. Only one thing can allow  a business to transcend the daily  brute struggle for survival: monopoly profits.

MONOPOLY CAPITALISM

So, a monopoly is good for everyone on the  inside, but what about everyone on the outside? Do outsized profits come at the expense of the rest  of society? Actually, yes: profits come out of customers’ wallets, and monopolies deserve  their bad reputation—but only in a world where nothing changes. In a static world,   a monopolist is just a rent collector. If  you corner the market for something, you can jack up the price; others will have no choice  but to buy from you. Think of the famous board game: deeds are shuffled  around from player to player,   but the board never changes. There’s no way to win by inventing a better kind of real estate development. The relative  values of the properties are  fixed for all time, so all you  can do is try to buy them up. But the world we live in is dynamic: it’s  possible to invent new and better things. Creative monopolists give customers more choices by adding  entirely new categories of abundance to the world. Creative monopolies aren’t just good for  the rest of society; they’re powerful engines for making it better. Even the government knows this: that’s   why one of its departments works hard to create monopolies (by granting patents to new inventions) even though another part hunts them down (by prosecuting antitrust cases). It’s possible to question whether anyone should really be awarded a legally enforceable monopoly simply for having been the first to think of something like a mobile software design. But it’s clear that something   like Apple’s monopoly profits from designing, producing, and marketing the iPhone were the reward for creating greater  abundance, not artificial  scarcity: customers were happy to finally have the  choice of paying high prices to get a smartphone that actually works. The dynamism of new monopolies itself explains   why old monopolies don’t strangle innovation. With Apple’s iOS at the forefront, the rise of mobile computing has  dramatically reduced Microsoft’s  decades-long operating system  dominance. Before that, IBM’s hardware monopoly of the ’60s and ’70s was overtaken by Microsoft’s software monopoly. AT&T had a monopoly on telephone service for most of the 20th century, but now anyone can   get a cheap cell phone plan from any number of providers. If the tendency of monopoly businesses   were to hold back progress, they would be dangerous and we’d be right to oppose them. But   the history of progress is a history of better monopoly businesses replacing incumbents.  Monopolies drive progress because the promise  of years or even decades of monopoly profits  provides a powerful incentive to innovate. Then  monopolies can keep innovating because profits  enable them to make the long-term plans and to  finance the ambitious research projects that firms  locked in competition can’t dream of. So why are economists obsessed with competition   as an ideal state? It’s a relic of history. Economists copied their mathematics from the work   of 19th-century physicists: they see individuals and businesses as interchangeable atoms,   not as unique creators. Their theories describe an equilibrium state of perfect competition because that’s what’s easy to model, not because it represents the best of business. But   it’s worth recalling that the  long-run equilibrium predicted by 19th-century physics was a  state in which all energy   is evenly distributed and everything comes to rest—also known as the heat death of the universe. Whatever your views on thermodynamics, it’s a powerful metaphor: in business,   equilibrium means stasis, and stasis  means death. If your industry is in a competitive equilibrium, the death of your  business won’t matter to the world; some other undifferentiated competitor will  always be ready to take your place.  Perfect equilibrium may describe the void that  is most of the universe. It may even characterize many businesses. But every new creation  takes place far from equilibrium. In the real world outside economic theory,   every business is successful exactly to  the extent that it does something others cannot. Monopoly is therefore not a  pathology or an exception. Monopoly is the condition of every successful business.  Tolstoy opens Anna Karenina by observing: “All  happy families are alike; each unhappy family is unhappy in its own way.” Business is the opposite.  All happy companies are different: each one earns a monopoly by solving a unique problem. All failed  companies are the same: they failed to escape competition.

Previous
Previous

2 PARTY LIKE IT’S 1999

Next
Next

4 THE IDEOLOGY OF COMPETITION